Jump to content

Ludwig von Mises

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Ludwig Von Mises)
Ludwig von Mises
Born
Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises

(1881-09-29)29 September 1881
Died10 October 1973(1973-10-10) (aged 92)
Resting placeFerncliff Cemetery, Hartsdale, Westchester County, New York, U.S
SpouseMargit von Mises
Relatives
Academic career
FieldEconomics
Political economy
Philosophy of science
Epistemology
Methodology
Rationalism
Logic
Classical liberalism
Libertarianism
Institution
School or
tradition
Austrian School
Alma materUniversity of Vienna
Doctoral
advisor
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
Doctoral
students
Other notable students
Influences
Contributions
Signature

Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises[n 1] (German: [ˈluːtvɪç fɔn ˈmiːzəs]; 29 September 1881 – 10 October 1973) was an Austrian-American economist, logician, sociologist and philosopher of economics of the Austrian school. Mises wrote and lectured extensively on the societal contributions of classical liberalism and the power of consumers.[1] He is best known for his work in praxeology, particularly for studies comparing communism and capitalism, as well as for being a defender of classical liberalism[2] in the face of rising illiberalism and authoritarianism throughout much of Europe during the 20th century.

Mises emigrated from Austria to the United States in 1940, fleeing from Nazis who on the first day the German Army entered Vienna rushed into the von Mises apartment in Vienna, apparently looking for him, and confiscated his library and papers. Mises was in Geneva, Switzerland at the time, but when the German invasion of France was about to leave Switzerland completely surrounded by Fascist and Nazi controlled territory, von Mises and his wife found it necessary to flee through France dodging German troops, to get to the US via Spain and Portugal.[3] Since the mid-20th century, both libertarian movements and the field of economics as a whole, have been strongly influenced by Mises's writings.[4] Mises's student Friedrich Hayek viewed Mises as one of the major figures in the revival of classical liberalism in the post-war era. Hayek's work The Transmission of the Ideals of Freedom (1951) pays high tribute to the influence of Mises in the 20th-century libertarian movement.[5] Economist Tyler Cowen lists his writings as "the most important works of the 20th century" and as "among the most important economics articles, ever".[6]

Mises's Private Seminar created a leading group of economists.[7] Many of its alumni, including Friedrich Hayek and Oskar Morgenstern, emigrated from Austria to the United States and Great Britain. Mises has been described as having approximately seventy close students in Austria.[8]

Mises received many honors throughout the course of his lifetime—honorary doctorates from Grove City College (1957), New York University (1963), and the University of Freiburg (1964) in Germany. His accomplishments were recognized in 1956 by his alma mater, the University of Vienna, when his doctorate was memorialized on its 50th anniversary and "renewed," a European tradition, and in 1962 by the Austrian government.  He was also cited in 1969 as "Distinguished Fellow" by the American Economic Association.[9]

Biography

[edit]

Early life

[edit]
Coat of arms of Ludwig von Mises's great-grandfather, Mayer Rachmiel Mises, awarded upon his 1881 ennoblement by Franz Joseph I of Austria

Ludwig von Mises was born on 29 September 1881 to Jewish parents in Lemberg, then in the Austro-Hungarian Kingdom of Galicia and Lodomeria. His great-grandfather Meyer Rachmiel Mises had been ennobled a few months before Ludwig's birth, receiving the honorific Edler (indicating a non-landed noble family), and the right to add the nobiliary particle von to his name; his family had been involved in financing and constructing railroads.[10] His mother Adele (née Landau) was a niece of Joachim Landau, a Liberal Party deputy to the Austrian Parliament.[11]: 3–9  His father Arthur von Mises was stationed in Lemberg as a construction engineer with the Czernowitz railway company.

By the age of 12, Mises spoke fluent German, Russian, Polish and French, read Latin and could understand Ukrainian.[12] Mises had a younger brother, Richard von Mises, who became a mathematician and a member of the Vienna Circle, and a probability theorist.[13]

Mises was educated at the Akademisches Gymnasium in Vienna from 1892 to 1900, before entering the University of Vienna, where he studied law and the social sciences, initially in preparation for a career as a civil servant.[14][15] There, he first encountered the works of Carl Menger, whose book Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre came to influence him significantly. Mises's father died in 1903. Three years later, Mises was awarded his doctorate from the school of law in 1906.[16] From 1913 to 1938, Mises was a professor at the university, during which he mentored Friedrich Hayek.[1]

Life in Europe

[edit]

In the years from 1904 to 1914, Mises attended lectures given by Austrian economist Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk.[17] He graduated in February 1906 (Juris Doctor) and started a career as a civil servant in Austria's financial administration.

After a few months, he left to take a trainee position in a Vienna law firm. During that time, Mises began lecturing on economics and in early 1909 joined the Austrian Chamber of Commerce and Industry, serving as economic advisor to the Austrian government until he left Austria in 1934.[18] During World War I, Mises served as a front officer in the Austro-Hungarian artillery and as an economic advisor to the War Department.[19]

Mises was chief economist for the Austrian Chamber of Commerce and was an economic advisor of Engelbert Dollfuss, the austrofascist Austrian Chancellor.[20] Later, Mises was economic advisor to Otto von Habsburg, the Christian democratic politician and claimant to the throne of Austria (which had been legally abolished in 1918 following the Great War).[3] In 1934, Mises left Austria for Geneva, Switzerland, where he was a professor at the Graduate Institute of International Studies until 1940. Mises was invited to the Colloque Walter Lippmann, organized in Paris in 1938, and was a founding member of the Mont Pelerin Society in 1947.[21]

While in Switzerland, Mises married Margit Herzfeld Serény, a former actress and widow of Ferdinand Serény. She was the mother of Gitta Sereny.[22]

World War I

[edit]

During World War I, Ludwig von Mises was drafted by the Austrian government, despite being ideologically and morally opposed to the war. Like many who served in the front lines,[23] he rarely spoke about his personal experiences, and even his Memoirs (1940) omits a detailed account of his time in the military. However, he briefly alluded to the harsh realities of war in his seminal work, Human Action (1949):

Nothing is fair in war. It is not just that God is for the big battalions and that those who are better equipped defeat poorly equipped adversaries. It is not just that those in the front line shed their life-blood in obscurity, while the commanders, comfortably located in headquarters hundreds of miles behind the trenches, gain glory and fame. It is not just that John is killed and Mark crippled for the rest of his life, while Paul returns home safe and sound and enjoys all the privileges accorded to veterans. It may be admitted that it is not "fair" that war enhances the profits of those entrepreneurs who contribute best to the equipment of the fighting forces. But it would be foolish to deny that the profit system produces the best weapons.[24]

In Memoirs (1940), the only thing he had to say about the war was how it affected his work:

By the end of 1917, I was no longer at the front, but worked in Vienna in the economics division of the Department of War. I wrote only two small essays during those years.[25]

The same chapter concludes with how he coped with his involuntary servitude fighting as the aggressor in a war he wanted nothing to do with, and includes a quote from Virgil that would go on to become the slogan of the Mises Institute in Alabama:

How one carries on in the face of unavoidable catastrophe is a matter of temperament. In high school, as was custom, I had chosen a verse by Virgil to be my motto: Tu ne cede malis sed contra audentior ito ("Do not give in to evil, but proceed ever more boldly against it"). I recalled these words during the darkest hours of the war.[26]

Work in the United States

[edit]
External videos
video icon Bettina Greaves on Ludwig von Mises's Life (1994)

In 1940, Mises and his wife left Austria, by then a territory of Nazi Germany, and emigrated to New York City in the United States.[1][11]: xi  He had come to the United States under a grant by the Rockefeller Foundation. Like many other classical liberal scholars who fled to the United States, he received support from the William Volker Fund to obtain a position in American universities.[27] Mises became a visiting professor at New York University and held this position from 1945 until his retirement in 1969, though he was not salaried by the university.[16] Businessman and libertarian commentator Lawrence Fertig, a member of the New York University Board of Trustees, funded Mises and his work.[28][29]

For part of this period, Mises studied currency issues for the Pan-Europa movement, which was led by Richard von Coudenhove-Kalergi, a fellow New York University faculty member and Austrian exile.[30] In 1947, Mises became one of the founding members of the Mont Pelerin Society.

In 1962, Mises received the Austrian Decoration for Science and Art for political economy[31] at the Austrian Embassy in Washington, D.C.[11]: 1034 

Mises retired from teaching at the age of 87[32] and died on October 10, 1973, at age 92. He is buried at Ferncliff Cemetery in Hartsdale, New York. Grove City College houses the 20,000-page archive of Mises papers and unpublished works.[33] The personal library of Mises was given to Hillsdale College as bequeathed in his will.[34][35]

At one time, Mises praised the work of writer Ayn Rand, and she generally looked on his work with favor, but the two had a volatile relationship, with strong disagreements for example over the moral basis of capitalism.[36] The two thinkers' disagreement reached a critical point during a dinner conversation where Mises reportedly lost his temper and called Rand a "silly little Jewish girl" after a heated argument, despite himself being Jewish.[37]

Creation of the Mises Institute

[edit]

As a result of the economic works of Ludwig Von Mises, the Mises Institute was founded in 1982 by Lew Rockwell, Burton Blumert, and Murray Rothbard, following a split between the Cato Institute and Rothbard, who had been one of the founders of the Cato Institute.[non-primary source needed] It was funded by Ron Paul.[38]

The Mises Institute offers thousands of free books written by Ludwig Von Mises, Murray Rothbard, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, and other prominent economists in e-book and audiobook format.[39] The Mises Institute also offers a series of summer seminars.[40]

Contributions and influence in economics

[edit]

Ludwig von Mises made significant contributions to the field of economics[41] initially by seeking to integrate the teachings of Carl Menger and Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk into the classical economic framework of his time.[42] He recognized the need to reformulate economic epistemology,[42] particularly in response to the challenges introduced by the subjective value theory and the subjectivity of individual agents.[11] Later, Mises made groundbreaking contributions to economic theory,[4] particularly in advancing the Austrian School of Economics by developing his own transformative ideas, including praxeology—a systematic framework for understanding human action[43]—and the economic calculation problem,[44] which challenged the feasibility of socialism.[45][46]

In 1920, Mises introduced the Economic Calculation Problem as a critique of socialist states which are based on planned economies and renunciations of the price mechanism.[47] In his first article "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth", Mises describes the nature of the price system under capitalism and describes how individual subjective values are translated into the objective information necessary for rational allocation of resources in society.[47] Mises argued the absence of market pricing results in inefficiencies within the economic system because central planners are deprived of the crucial information regarding opportunity costs needed to make informed decisions about resource allocation.[47] He wrote that "rational economic activity is impossible in a socialist commonwealth".[47] Mises developed his critique of socialism more completely in his 1922 book Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, arguing that the market price system is an expression of praxeology and cannot be replicated by any form of bureaucracy.[48][2]

Throughout his life[14][24][47][49] Mises argued that only a free market system, where individuals are free to pursue their own interests, can efficiently allocate resources and maximize social welfare.[50] He believed that laissez-faire capitalism is the only system that allows individuals to express their intersubjective appraisals of goods and services in an open market, thereby creating a nexus of price signals based off of the relative exchange ratios between goods. These price signals are essential for coordinating the inherently incomparable[51] subjective valuations that different individuals place on the same external objects.[52] In a market, these subjective rankings are transformed into numerical values—prices—that can be objectively compared.[53] This mechanism enables the continuous alignment of the open-ended coordination problem posed by millions of disparate individual preferences.[54][55] Unlike a centrally planned system, which assumes a final equilibrium which is to be planned towards,[56] the free market remains in constant flux,[57] continuously adjusting to changes in preferences and conditions.[58] Mises's praxeological approach and reformulation of the economic problem has had a profound impact on the Austrian school of economics.[59][60]

Mises revived and expanded the term Catallactics, which originally came from the greek word katallasso, meaning "to exchange" or "to reconcile."[61] Catallaxy explains prices as they are, rather than as they "should" be.[62] By adopting a value-neutral stance, it does not judge whether a price is "too high" or "too low"; instead, it seeks to explain why a price exists at a particular level based on the interplay of supply and demand. This framework considers both the material conditions influencing the availability of goods and services (supply) and the subjective preferences, values, and willingness to pay of individuals (demand).[58] Prices emerge where these factors align between buyers and sellers, reflecting the conditions for exchange at a specific time and place.[63]

Contrast with Normative Economics: By focusing on prices as they are, catallactics aimed to avoid the pitfalls of culturally or ideologically biased assumptions, where economic policies are designed around idealized notions of what "ought" to happen, (e.g. some works that aim to prescribe the economy, not just describe it:[64][65][66][67][68][69]) which Mises argued carried them outside of the realm of the descriptive (or wertfrei) sciences.[70]

"Economics is not about what ought to be, but about what is. It describes and analyzes the reality of human action, without imposing any personal valuations or ethical imperatives."[71]

For Mises, introducing normative judgments—such as declaring certain prices "fair" or "unfair"—transforms economics from a descriptive science into an ideological discourse.

"The ultimate decisions, the valuations and the choosing of ends, are beyond the scope of any science."[71]

This approach redefined economics not as the study of wealth or resources in the abstract, but as the analysis of voluntary exchanges of these resources within the division of labor.[72] His work on catallactics became a cornerstone of Austrian economics, influencing subsequent theories on entrepreneurship,[73] knowledge,[45] and the limits of government intervention.[74]

Mises was also a forerunner in the movement to unite microeconomics and macroeconomics,[58] arguing that macroeconomic phenomena have microeconomic foundations[75]—nearly 50 years before this perspective was widely adopted by mainstream economics.[76]

In his magnum opus Human Action (1949), Mises established praxeology as the foundational methodology for the social sciences,[77] offering a systematic approach to understanding human behavior and decision-making. This work laid the groundwork for a comprehensive economic theory[78] that accounted for the subjective nature of value and the complexity of individual choices, marking a significant departure[17] from the objective models of classical economics.[79][80] Mises used praxeology to further critique socialism, arguing that it is fundamentally flawed because it treats economics as a solvable, static problem[81] akin to mathematical or engineering challenges.[51] Instead, he argued, economics involves an open-ended coordination process that aims to align the diverse and equally valid[82] subjective appraisals of millions of individuals.[57] However, while praxeology has been influential within the Austrian school of economics, it is not widely adopted in contemporary economic practice,[83] which predominantly relies on empirical and mathematical methods to analyze and predict economic phenomena.[84] Most mainstream economists view praxeology as lacking empirical validation and testability, thereby limiting its acceptance as a scientific approach within the broader discipline.[85]

In his 1956 book The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality, Ludwig von Mises explored the roots of intellectual opposition to the free market, particularly in American society.[86] Mises argued that some people resent the burden of freedom, preferring the perceived security of a caste-like system where individual responsibility for one's position in the division of labor is minimized. He believed that people who are content in their position, i.e., who have forgone upward social mobility, may yearn for capitalism to be a rigid caste system, allowing them to blame "the system" or "society" for their low wages or unfulfilled ambitions. Mises also contended that throughout most of human history, wealth was often accumulated through exploitation, war, and conquest.[87] As a result, our cognitive biases have not yet adapted to the modern world of rule of law and peaceful exchange, leading to a subconscious suspicion of wealth as being illegitimately obtained. This suspicion persists even though, in a free market, individuals can accumulate wealth through mutually beneficial exchange and technological innovation. Mises also criticized the romanticization of artisan goods, arguing that mass production, driven by consumer demand, has democratized access to goods that in previous centuries were available only to a small aristocratic few.[88] He suggested that critics who lament the availability of inexpensive, mass-produced goods fail to appreciate the benefits these goods bring, as they enable a higher standard of living for the general population who may not be able to afford handcrafted goods.[1]

Friends and students of Mises in Europe included Wilhelm Röpke and Alfred Müller-Armack (advisors to German chancellor Ludwig Erhard), Jacques Rueff (monetary advisor to Charles de Gaulle), Gottfried Haberler (later a professor at Harvard), Lionel, Lord Robbins (of the London School of Economics), Italian President Luigi Einaudi, and Leonid Hurwicz, recipient of the 2007 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences.[89] Economist and political theorist Friedrich Hayek first came to know Mises while working as his subordinate at a government office dealing with Austria's post-World War I debt. While toasting Mises at a party in 1956, Hayek said: "I came to know him as one of the best educated and informed men I have ever known".[3]: 219–220  Mises's seminars in Vienna fostered lively discussion among established economists there. The meetings were also visited by other important economists who happened to be traveling through Vienna.

At his New York University seminar and at informal meetings at his apartment, Mises attracted college and high school students who had heard of his European reputation. They listened while he gave carefully prepared lectures from notes.[90][91][n 2]

Ludwig von Mises acknowledged that, by the time of his writing, many core concepts from the Austrian school of economics had been integrated into mainstream economic thought.[92] He noted that the distinctions between the Austrian school and other economic traditions had blurred, making the label "Austrian" more of a historical reference than a marker of a distinct, contemporary doctrine.[93] This integration occurred as concepts like marginal utility, opportunity cost, and the importance of subjective value became widely accepted among economists.[76]

Philosophical views

[edit]

Ludwig von Mises was a prominent advocate of methodological individualism,[28] a principle that asserts all social phenomena result from the actions and decisions of individuals.[94] He believed that only individuals act, and thus, collective entities such as nations, classes, or races do not possess independent agency.[95] This perspective formed the basis of his economic and social theories, rejecting any form of collectivism that attributed agency to groups rather than to individuals.[96]

His rejection of collectivism led him to be a vocal critic of what he termed "polylogism;" the idea that different groups of people have fundamentally different ways of thinking and thus different logics.[97] He rejected the notion that there could be distinct sciences or truths based on race, class, or nationality, such as "Jewish science" or "German science".[98] Mises believed in the universality of logic and reason, asserting that the principles of economics and science are objective and apply universally, regardless of the cultural or ethnic background of the individuals studying them.[43]

Ludwig von Mises is credited[99] with transforming praxeology into a comprehensive framework for understanding economics and human behavior, making it central to the Austrian school of economics.[43] He provided it with a clear definition and methodology, focusing on the logical structure of human action and choice.[4] Thus, while the term existed before Mises, he is largely responsible for its current understanding and significance in economic theory.[58] Mises argued that economics is a branch of praxeology, which studies the implications of the fact that individuals act purposefully.[100] Mises maintained that economic laws are derived from the self-evident axiom[101] that humans engage in purposeful behavior to achieve desired ends.[102][103][104] This approach led him to oppose empirical and statistical methods as primary tools in economic theory, arguing that these could not establish economic laws due to the uniqueness of historical events.[105]

In defense of his teleological understanding of human action, he highlighted the difference in using physics to study inanimate objects, and its application to the study of an introspective being which reflects upon and changes its reactions to receiving the same stimulus twice:

The objects of the natural sciences react to stimuli according to regular patterns. No such regularity, as far as man can see, determines the reaction of man to various stimuli. Ideas are frequently, but not always, the reaction of an individual to a stimulation provided by his natural environment. But even such reactions are not uniform. Different individuals, and the same individual at various periods of his life, react to the same stimulus in a different way. As there is no discernible regularity in the emergence and concatenation of ideas and judgments of value, and therefore also not in the succession and concatenation of human acts, the role that experience plays in the study of human action is radically different from that which it plays in the natural sciences.[106]

He would eventually go into enormous detail defending this distinction in his work Epistemological Problems of Economics (1933), Theory and History (1957), and again in The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science (1962) which included further explication such as:

Man alone has the faculty to build a purpose and to aim at its realization. Stones are moved by an impulse from outside. Animals, in their behavior, follow the impulses of their senses and appetites. Man is the only being who can control his impulses and passions, who can suppress a natural inclination and act contrary to it.[107]

This perspective placed him in contrast with the positivist approach, which emphasizes empirical data and observation as the foundation of scientific knowledge.[84] This rift in epistemology has led some to argue[108] that Mises attempted to usher in a paradigm shift in the science of economics—but this is not the direction the field as a whole has since gone.[109][110][111][85] Because of this, most academics within the economics community implicitly consider the work which comes out of the Mises Institute and other followers of Mises, to simply not be economics.[83] Mises's followers operate under a different paradigm and follow an opposed rule set to those operating under positivist economics.[112] His objections can be seen as an early precursor to more modern critiques such as the famous Lucas critique.[113]

Political views

[edit]

Ludwig von Mises was a steadfast advocate of liberalism, particularly classical liberalism.[14] He believed that while Marx provided a powerful critique of capitalism, he failed to offer a constructive vision[56] of a socialist society that could be practically implemented.[114][115] To learn from this mistake, after publishing his lengthy critique of socialism, Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution,[citation needed] in his next book, Liberalism (1927), Mises articulated a positive vision of free society rooted in individual liberty, private property, free markets, and limited government coercion. He argued that these principles are essential for creating a peaceful and prosperous society.[14]

Key aspects of Mises's defense of liberalism

[edit]

Mises advocated for economic non-interventionism[116] and was a staunch anti-imperialist.[117] He viewed the Great War as a watershed moment in human history, arguing that it marked a significant departure from previous conflicts due to the advanced technology employed. His experience in the first World War led to a lifelong obsession of finding a workable doctrine of peace among nations, which at the same time would not ask any individual nation to give up their own self interest. Regarding the birth of total war, Mises wrote:

War has become more fearful and destructive than ever before because it is now waged with all the means of the highly developed technique that the free economy has created. Bourgeois civilization has built railroads and electric power plants, has invented explosives and airplanes, in order to create wealth. Imperialism has placed the tools of peace in the service of destruction. With modern means, it would be easy to wipe out humanity at one blow.[118]

Comments about fascism

[edit]

Marxists Herbert Marcuse and Perry Anderson as well as German writer Claus-Dieter Krohn accused Mises of writing approvingly of Italian fascism, especially for its suppression of leftist elements, in his 1927 book Liberalism.[119] In 2009, economist J. Bradford DeLong and sociologist Richard Seymour repeated the accusation.[120]

Mises, in his 1927 book Liberalism, wrote:[121]

It cannot be denied that Fascism and similar movements aiming at the establishment of dictatorships are full of the best intentions and that their intervention has, for the moment, saved European civilization. The merit that Fascism has thereby won for itself will live on eternally in history. But though its policy has brought salvation for the moment, it is not of the kind which could promise continued success. Fascism was an emergency makeshift. To view it as something more would be a fatal error.

Mises biographer Jörg Guido Hülsmann says that critics who suggest that Mises supported fascism are "absurd" as he notes that the full quote describes fascism as dangerous. He notes that Mises said it was a "fatal error" to think that it was more than an "emergency makeshift" against up and coming communism and socialism as exemplified by the Bolsheviks in Russia and the surging communists of Germany.[11]: 560  Hülsmann writes in Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism that Mises had been a card-carrying member of the Fatherland Front party and that this was "probably mandatory for all employees of public and semi-public organizations."[122]

However, this paragraph is also in keeping with a theme that runs through his work: he consistently refrained from imputing bad intentions to those he disagreed with, regardless of how fascistic or homicidal their policy outcomes were. He took pain to more than once explicitly acknowledge the good intentions of totalitarians and socialists of all walks, such as when he wrote:

Socialists have full right to be called righteous men. They do not wish to profit personally from their ideology. They seek nothing for themselves. They want to benefit the public. They have nothing but scorn for the riches that the capitalistic order of production offers them. They live for their idea, and if they sacrifice anything it is their own well-being. They are the idealists among our contemporaries.[123]

Mises, in his 1927 book Liberalism, also wrote of fascism:[121]

Repression by brute force is always a confession of the inability to make use of the better weapons of the intellect—better because they alone give promise of final success. This is the fundamental error from which Fascism suffers and which will ultimately cause its downfall. The victory of Fascism in a number of countries is only an episode in the long series of struggles over the problem of property. The next episode will be the victory of Communism. The ultimate outcome of the struggle, however, will not be decided by arms, but by ideas. It is ideas that group men into fighting factions, that press the weapons into their hands, and that determine against whom and for whom the weapons shall be used. It is they alone, and not arms, that, in the last analysis, turn the scales. So much for the domestic policy of Fascism. That its foreign policy, based as it is on the avowed principle of force in international relations, cannot fail to give rise to an endless series of wars that must destroy all of modern civilization requires no further discussion. To maintain and further raise our present level of economic development, peace among nations must be assured. But they cannot live together in peace if the basic tenet of the ideology by which they are governed is the belief that one's own nation can secure its place in the community of nations by force alone.

In his earlier work, Socialism (1922), Mises also made a similar remark with more context, saying that Mussolini did his best to prop up Austria-Hungary as a means of protecting Italian speaking minorities, but regardless concludes that he was one the most wretched figures in history:

Only those Italians are free to blame Mussolini who begin to understand that the only means of protecting the Italian-speaking minorities in the Littoral districts of Austria against the threatening annihilation by the Slavonic majorities was to preserve the integrity of the Austrian state, whose constitution guaranteed equal rights to all linguistic groups. Mussolini was one of the most wretched figures of history.[124]

In regards to Nazism, Mises called on the Allies in his 1944 book Omnipotent Government to "smash Nazism" and to "fight desperately until the Nazi power is completely broken".[125]

In his Notes and recollections, Mises wrote of his experience being personally persecuted by the Nazis for his attacks on Italian Fascism and the National Socialist party:

The Nazis looted my library and collections. The manuscripts I had worked on during my years in Vienna were lost. I was deeply affected by these losses. However, I managed to escape and start anew. The Nazis chased me out of my home country and off the continent. I had to leave everything behind, but I found refuge in the United States, where I could continue my work and fight for the ideas of liberty.[126]

Reception

[edit]

Debates about Mises's arguments

[edit]

Economic historian Bruce Caldwell wrote that in the mid-20th century, with the ascendance of positivism and Keynesianism, Mises came to be regarded by many as the "archetypal 'unscientific' economist".[127] In a 1957 review of his book The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality, The Economist said of Mises: "Professor von Mises has a splendid analytical mind and an admirable passion for liberty; but as a student of human nature he is worse than null and as a debater he is of Hyde Park standard".[128] Conservative commentator Whittaker Chambers published a similarly negative review of that book in the National Review, stating that Mises's thesis that anti-capitalist sentiment was rooted in "envy" epitomized "know-nothing conservatism" at its "know-nothingest".[129] More recent commenters, such as Tyler Cowen of George Mason University, have listed it alongside Socialism (1922), and Liberalism (1927) as one of the most important books of the 20th century, despite describing Human Action (1949) as "cranky and dogmatic".[6] In the same blog post, Cowen states that:

Socialism is still the best and also historically most important critique of socialism, ever. His earlier articles about the impossibility of economic calculation under socialism are among the most important economics articles, ever.[6]

Scholar Scott Scheall called economist Terence Hutchison "the most persistent critic of Mises's apriorism",[101]: 233  starting in Hutchison's 1938 book The Significance and Basic Postulates of Economic Theory and in later publications such as his 1981 book The Politics and Philosophy of Economics: Marxians, Keynesians, and Austrians.[101]: 242  Scheall noted that Friedrich Hayek, later in his life (after Mises died), also expressed reservations about Mises's apriorism, such as in a 1978 interview where Hayek said that he "never could accept the... almost eighteenth-century rationalism in his [Mises's] argument".[101]: 233–234 

In a 1978 interview, Hayek said about Mises's book Socialism:

At first we all felt he was frightfully exaggerating and even offensive in tone. You see, he hurt all our deepest feelings, but gradually he won us around, although for a long time I had to – I just learned he was usually right in his conclusions, but I was not completely satisfied with his argument.[130]

Economist Milton Friedman considered Mises inflexible in his thinking, but added that Mises's difficult life, persecution by Nazis, and lack of acceptance by academia are the likely culprits:

The story I remember best happened at the initial Mont Pelerin meeting when he got up and said, "You're all a bunch of socialists." We were discussing the distribution of income, and whether you should have progressive income taxes. Some of the people there were expressing the view that there could be a justification for it. Another occasion which is equally telling: Fritz Machlup was a student of Mises's, one of his most faithful disciples. At one of the Mont Pelerin meetings, Machlup gave a talk in which I think he questioned the idea of a gold standard; he came out in favor of floating exchange rates. Mises was so mad he wouldn't speak to Machlup for three years. Some people had to come around and bring them together again. It's hard to understand; you can get some understanding of it by taking into account how people like Mises were persecuted in their lives.[131]

Economist Murray Rothbard, who studied under Mises, agreed he was uncompromising, but disputes reports of his abrasiveness. In his words, Mises was "unbelievably sweet, constantly finding research projects for students to do, unfailingly courteous, and never bitter" about the discrimination he received at the hands of the economic establishment of his time.[132]

After Mises died, his widow Margit quoted a passage that he had written about Benjamin Anderson. She said it best described Mises's own personality:

His most eminent qualities were his inflexible honesty, his unhesitating sincerity. He never yielded. He always freely enunciated what he considered to be true. If he had been prepared to suppress or only to soften his criticisms of popular, but irresponsible, policies, the most influential positions and offices would have been offered him. But he never compromised.[133]

Critics more broadly argue that praxeology's reliance on a priori reasoning and rejection of empirical methods limit its ability to test and validate economic theories. This critique is grounded in the belief that economic theories should be subject to Popperian falsification, as seen in mainstream economics, which emphasizes data-driven analysis and the use of econometrics.[134] Even within the Austrian tradition, there are debates about the extent and application of praxeology.[135] For example, Friedrich Hayek, while sympathetic to Austrian principles, was more open to incorporating empirical evidence and saw limitations in a strictly a priori approach.[136] In his book The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason, Hayek critiques the overconfidence in the application of scientific methods to social sciences, including economics. While he does not explicitly target praxeology, his arguments suggest a more skeptical view of purely deductive methodologies. Hayek emphasizes the complexity of social phenomena and the limitations of any one method, advocating for a more pluralistic approach to economic inquiry.[77]

The Austrian School's methodological differences, particularly its reluctance to engage with quantitative methods, have led to its marginalization within the broader economics discipline. This isolation is a result of the school's focus on verbal logic and theoretical purity, which many mainstream economists view as insufficiently rigorous.[137] Other commenters such as Eric Weinstein and Peter Thiel have remarked about the broader issue of dogmatism within Austrian economics. Weinstein emphasized the importance of being open to new ideas and criticized the tendency within Austrian economics to dismiss other methodologies.[138] While the Austrian's prosaic approach provides valuable insights into the decision-making process, econometrically-minded critics argue that it lacks the predictive power of other economic models that rely on more objective measures. This subjectivism can make it challenging to formulate generalizable laws or predictions.[134]

Works

[edit]

Books

Book reviews

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b c d "Ludwig von Mises". Encyclopædia Britannica. 7 June 2023. Retrieved 2023-06-29.
  2. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich A. "Introduction." In Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, by Ludwig von Mises. London: Jonathan Cape, 1936.
  3. ^ a b c Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House Publishers, 1976; 2nd enlarged ed., Cedar Falls, IA: Center for Futures Education, 1984. ISBN 978-0-915513-00-0. OCLC 11668538
  4. ^ a b c Cowen, Tyler. "Review of Human Action." Journal of Economic Literature 38, no. 4 (2000): 1127-1132.
  5. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. (2012). "The Transmission of the Ideals of Economic Freedom". Econ Journal Watch. 9 (2): 163–169.
  6. ^ a b c Cowen, Tyler (October 16, 2022). "Overrated or underrated?". Marginal Revolution.
  7. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (2013). Notes and Recollections (PDF). Liberty Fund. p. 69. ISBN 978-0-86597-853-9.
  8. ^ Beller, Steven (1989). Vienna and the Jews, 1867–1938: A Cultural History. Cambridge University Press.
  9. ^ Greaves, Bettina Bien. "Preface to the Third Edition." In Liberalism: In the Classical Tradition, by Ludwig von Mises, 3rd ed., Liberty Fund, 1985.
  10. ^ Hülsmann, Jörg (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Auburn, AL: Mises Institute. ISBN 978-1-61016-389-7.
  11. ^ a b c d e Hülsmann, Jörg Guido (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-1-933550-18-3.
  12. ^ Erik Ritter von Kuehnelt-Leddihn, "The Cultural Background of Ludwig von Mises", The Ludwig von Mises Institute, p. 1
  13. ^ "Richard von Mises". Encyclopædia Britannica. Retrieved 8 August 2013.
  14. ^ a b c d Von Mises, Ludwig; Goddard, Arthur (1979). Liberalism: A Socio-Economic Exposition (2 ed.). Sheed Andrews and McMeel. ISBN 978-0-8362-5106-7.
  15. ^ Hülsmann, Jörg (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Ludwig von Mises Institute. pp. 33, 60, 62. ISBN 978-1-61016-389-7.
  16. ^ a b "Biography of Ludwig von Mises (1881–1973) ('Chronology')". Mises.org. August 2007. Retrieved 21 July 2013.
  17. ^ a b Mises, Ludwig von, The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics, Arlington House, 1969, reprinted by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1984, p. 10, Rothbard, Murray, The Essential Ludwig von Mises, 2nd printing, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1983, p. 30.
  18. ^ Rothbard, Murray, The Essential Ludwig von Mises, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 25.
  19. ^ Mises in Wartime, Mises Institute
  20. ^ "The Free Market: Meaning of the Mises Papers, The". Mises.org. April 1997. Retrieved 2009-11-26.
  21. ^ Mirowski, Philip; Plehwe , Dieter (2009). The Road From Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective. Harvard University Press. p. 13. ISBN 978-0-674-03318-4.
  22. ^ Mises, Margit von. My Years with Ludwig von Mises. New Rochelle, NY: Arlington House Publishers, 1976. [ISBN missing]
  23. ^ Christensen, Tricia (2024). "Why are Veterans Reluctant to Discuss Their War Experiences?".
  24. ^ a b Mises, Ludwig von (1966), Human Action: A Treatise on Economics, The Scholars edition. (Auburn, Alabama. Ludwig von Mises Institute), Pp. 823.
  25. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. (2009) Memoirs. Translated by Arlene Oost-Zinner. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, Pp. 52.
  26. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. (2009) Memoirs. Translated by Arlene Oost-Zinner. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, Pp. 55.
  27. ^ Kitch, Edmund W. (April 1983). "The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1932–1970". Journal of Law and Economics. 26 (1): 163–234. doi:10.1086/467030. S2CID 153525815.
  28. ^ a b Moss, Laurence S. "Introduction". The Economics of Ludwig von Mises: Toward a Critical Reappraisal. Sheed and Ward, 1976.
  29. ^ North, Gary. "Mises on Money". LewRockwell.com. 21 January 2002 [1]
  30. ^ Coudenhove-Kalergi, Richard Nikolaus, Graf von (1953). An idea conquers the world. London: Hutchinson. p. 247.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  31. ^ Kurien Society of Science and Art website Archived 2020-10-30 at the Wayback Machine, Listing of recipients of the Austrian Decoration for Science and Art; Google Translated page, accessed June 5, 2013.
  32. ^ Rothbard, Murray, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 61.
  33. ^ Austrian Student Scholars Conference Announcement Archived 2013-08-02 at the Wayback Machine, Grove City College website, 2013, accessed June 8, 2013.
  34. ^ "About – Collections – Mossey Library". lib.hillsdale.edu. Retrieved 2016-07-26.
  35. ^ http://www.iea.org.uk/sites/default/files/publications/files/upldbook514pdf.pdf [bare URL PDF]
  36. ^ Jennifer Burns (2009). Goddess of the Market: Ayn Rand and the American Right. Oxford University Press. pp. 106, 141. ISBN 978-0-19-974089-5.
  37. ^ Boettke, Peter (2016). "Mises, Rand, and the 20th Century".
  38. ^ "The Story of the Mises Institute".
  39. ^ "Books & Library". Mises Institute. Archived from the original on Jan 24, 2022. Retrieved 2022-01-24.
  40. ^ "Summer Seminar Series". 20 July 2017.
  41. ^ Moss, Laurence S., editor. The Economics of Ludwig von Mises: Toward a Critical Reappraisal. Kansas City: Sheed and Ward, Inc., 1976. ISBN 978-0-8362-0804-7
  42. ^ a b Huerta de Soto, Jesús, editor. The Meaning of Ludwig von Mises: Contributions in Economics, Epistemology, Sociology, and Political Philosophy. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2009. ISBN 978-1-933550-17-7 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  43. ^ a b c Mises, Ludwig von. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. 3rd rev. ed. Chicago: Henry Regnery Company, 1966.
  44. ^ Lavoie, Don. Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered. Cambridge University Press, 1985.
  45. ^ a b Friedrich Hayek, "The Use of Knowledge in Society," American Economic Review, 1945
  46. ^ Friedrich A. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism. University of Chicago Press, 1988.
  47. ^ a b c d e Von Mises, Ludwig (1990). Economic calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth (PDF). Ludwig von Mises Institute. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2014-12-16. Retrieved 2008-09-08.
  48. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Bureaucracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1944.
  49. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1922) Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Translated by J. Kahane. New edition, enlarged with an Epilogue. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1951. Pp. 117.
  50. ^ Johansson, Per-Olov. An Introduction to Modern Welfare Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991. ISBN 978-0-521-35536-7 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  51. ^ a b Sowell, Thomas. Economic Facts and Fallacies. 2nd ed. New York: Basic Books, 2011. ISBN 978-0-465-01958-4 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  52. ^ Bohm, Peter. Social Efficiency: A Concise Introduction to Welfare Economics. London: Macmillan, 1973. ISBN 978-0-333-13416-5 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  53. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory. Principles of Microeconomics. 8th ed. Boston: Cengage Learning, 2018. [ISBN missing]
  54. ^ Feldman, Allan M., and Serrano, Roberto. Welfare Economics and Social Choice Theory. 2nd ed. New York: Springer, 2006. ISBN 978-0-387-25905-2 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  55. ^ O'Driscoll Jr., Gerald P. Economics as a Coordination Problem: The Contributions of Friedrich A. Hayek. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, Inc., 1977. ISBN 978-0-8362-0815-3
  56. ^ a b Shmelev, Nikolai, and Popov, Vladimir. The Turning Point: Revitalizing the Soviet Economy. 1st ed. New York: Doubleday, 1989. ISBN 0-385-24654-4
  57. ^ a b Sowell, Thomas. Basic Economics: A Common Sense Guide to the Economy. 5th ed. New York: Basic Books, 2015. ISBN 978-0-465-05661-9 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  58. ^ a b c d Rothbard, Murray N. Man, Economy, and State: A Treatise on Economic Principles. Princeton, NJ: D. Van Nostrand, 1962.
  59. ^ Boettke, Peter J. F. A. Hayek: Economics, Political Economy and Social Philosophy. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2018. ISBN 978-1-137-41160-0
  60. ^ Sowell, Thomas. Intellectuals and Society. 2nd ed. New York: Basic Books, 2012. [ISBN missing].
  61. ^ Hayek, F. A. Law, Legislation and Liberty: A New Statement of the Liberal Principles of Justice and Political Economy. University of Chicago Press, 1973.
  62. ^ Buchanan, James M. Cost and Choice: An Inquiry in Economic Theory. University of Chicago Press, 1969.
  63. ^ Boettke, Peter J. Living Economics: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow. Independent Institute, 2012.
  64. ^ Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom. Knopf, 1999.
  65. ^ Keynes, John Maynard. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Macmillan, 1936.
  66. ^ Marx, Karl. Das Kapital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume I. Translated by Samuel Moore and Edward Aveling, edited by Friedrich Engels, Progress Publishers, 1867.
  67. ^ Robinson, Joan. Economic Philosophy. Penguin Books, 1962.
  68. ^ Piketty, Thomas. Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
  69. ^ Mill, John Stuart. Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. John W. Parker, 1848.
  70. ^ Weber, Max. "Objectivity" in Social Science and Social Policy. In The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Translated and edited by Edward A. Shils and Henry A. Finch, Free Press, 1949.
  71. ^ a b Human Action (Chapter 2, "The Epistemological Problems of the Sciences of Human Action")
  72. ^ Vaughn, Karen I. Austrian Economics in America: The Migration of a Tradition. Cambridge University Press, 1994.
  73. ^ Kirzner, Israel M. Competition and Entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press, 1973.
  74. ^ Lavoie, Don. National Economic Planning: What is Left? Ballinger Publishing Company, 1985.
  75. ^ G. C. Harcourt, editor. The Microeconomic Foundations of Macroeconomics. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 1977. ISBN 978-0-333-21536-4.
  76. ^ a b Cowen, Tyler, and Tabarrok, Alex. Modern Principles of Economics. 6th ed. New York: Macmillan Learning, 2024. [ISBN missing].
  77. ^ a b Hayek, Friedrich A. The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the Abuse of Reason. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press, 1952.
  78. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. "Ludwig von Mises: A Last Knight of Liberalism." Reason, October 1973.
  79. ^ Smith, Adam. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell, 1776. Book I, Chapter V.
  80. ^ Mill, John Stuart. Principles of Political Economy. John W. Parker, 1848..
  81. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. The Pure Theory of Capital. University of Chicago Press, 1941.
  82. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. Individualism and Economic Order. University of Chicago Press, 1948.
  83. ^ a b Gorz, André. Critique of Economic Reason. Verso, 1989.
  84. ^ a b Angrist, Joshua D., and Jörn-Steffen Pischke. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion. Princeton University Press, 2009
  85. ^ a b Heyne, Paul, Peter Boettke, and David Prychitko. The Economic Way of Thinking. 13th ed., Pearson, 2014.
  86. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality. Van Nostrand, 1956.
  87. ^ Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World. Penguin Books, 2008. ISBN 978-1-59420-192-9.
  88. ^ Caldwell, Bruce, editor. Mont Pèlerin 1947: Transcripts of the Founding Meeting of the Mont Pèlerin Society. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 2022. ISBN 978-0-8179-2484-3
  89. ^ Rothbard, Murray, Ludwig von Mises: Scholar, Creator, Hero, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1988, p. 67.
  90. ^ Vaughn, Karen I (1998). Austrian Economics in America. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-63765-7. pp. 66–67.
  91. ^ Reisman, George, Capitalism: a Treatise on Economics, "Introduction", Jameson Books, 1996; and Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984, pp. 136–137.
  92. ^ Mises, Ludwig von, The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics, Arlington House, 1969, reprinted by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1984, p. 62
  93. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. The Collected Works of F.A. Hayek. Various editors. University of Chicago Press, various volumes.
  94. ^ Ferguson, William D. The Political Economy of Collective Action, Inequality, and Development. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2020. ISBN 978-1-5036-1092-1 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  95. ^ Olson, Mancur. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965. ISBN 978-0-674-53751-4.
  96. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1957, pp. 44-47.
  97. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1957, pp. 119-121.
  98. ^ Gimbel, Steven. Einstein's Jewish Science: Physics at the Intersection of Politics and Religion. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2013.
  99. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. University of Chicago Press, 1967.
  100. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. Scholar's Edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998. Pp. 11-13.
  101. ^ a b c d Scheall, Scott (July 2017). "What is extreme about Mises's extreme apriorism?". Journal of Economic Methodology. 24 (3): 226–249. doi:10.1080/1350178X.2017.1356439. S2CID 151703666.
  102. ^ Linsbichler, Alexander. Was Ludwig von Mises a Conventionalist? A New Analysis of the Epistemology of the Austrian School of Economics. Vienna: Springer, 2017. [ISBN missing].
  103. ^ Mises Institute. "Rothbard's Account of the Action Axiom: A Neo-Aristotelian-Thomistic Defense." The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. Auburn, AL: Mises Institute, 2023.
  104. ^ Facchini, François. "Apriorism, Introspection, and the Axiom of Action: A Realist Solution." The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 10, no. 3 (2007): 234-249.
  105. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. Scholar's Edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998. pp. 30-36.
  106. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Epistemological Problems of Economics. Translated by George Reisman. 3rd ed. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2003. Preface to the English-language edition, p. lxvi. ISBN 0-945466-36-6.
  107. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1962). The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science: An Essay on Method (Princeton: D. Van Nostrand), p. 79.
  108. ^ Rothbard, Murray N. (2000), Egalitarianism as a Revolt Against Nature and Other Essays, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
  109. ^ Berndt, Ernst R. The Practice of Econometrics: Classic and Contemporary. Addison-Wesley, 1991.
  110. ^ Imbens, Guido W., and Donald B. Rubin. Causal Inference for Statistics, Social, and Biomedical Sciences: An Introduction. Cambridge University Press, 2015.
  111. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory. Principles of Economics. 8th ed., Cengage Learning, 2021.
  112. ^ Caldwell, Bruce, editor. Austrian Economics: Tensions and New Directions. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1990.
  113. ^ Lucas, Robert E., Jr. "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique." In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, edited by Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, 19–46. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1976. [ISBN missing].
  114. ^ Megill, Allan. Karl Marx: The Burden of Reason (Why Marx Rejected Politics and the Market). Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2002. ISBN 978-0-7425-1587-2 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  115. ^ Del Águila Marchena, Levy. Communism, Political Power and Personal Freedom in Marx. Palgrave Macmillan, 2019. ISBN 978-3-030-19252-3 Parameter error in {{ISBN}}: checksum
  116. ^ "Why Intervention Persists". 2005-03-16.
  117. ^ "The Anti-Imperialism of Mises". 2013-06-24.
  118. ^ "Ludwig von Mises on World War I | Ludwig von Mises". 2017-04-06.
  119. ^ Ralph Raico, "Mises on Fascism, Democracy, and Other Questions, Journal of Libertarian Studies (1996) 12:1 pp. 1–27
  120. ^ Richard Seymour, [The Meaning of Cameron], (Zero Books, John Hunt, London, 2010), p. 32, ISBN 1-84694-456-2
  121. ^ a b Ludwig von Mises, "Liberalism", Chapter 10, The Argument of Fascism, 1927.
  122. ^ Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism (2007) p. 677
  123. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1981). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, trans. J. Kahane (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund), p. 499.
  124. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1922) Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Translated by J. Kahane. New edition, enlarged with an Epilogue. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1951. Pp. 575.
  125. ^ von Mises, Ludwig (1944). Omnipotent Government: The Rise of the Total State and Total War (PDF). United States: Liberty Fund. p. 264 (282 for the pdf). ISBN 978-0-86597-754-9.
  126. ^ Mises, Ludwig von. Notes and Recollections. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1978.
  127. ^ Caldwell, Bruce (2004). Hayek's Challenge. The University of Chicago Press. pp. 125–126. ISBN 978-0-226-09191-4.
  128. ^ "Liberalism in Caricature", The Economist
  129. ^ Quoted in Sam Tanenhaus, Whittaker Chambers: A Biography, (Random House, New York, 1997), p. 500. ISBN 978-0-375-75145-5.
  130. ^ UCLA Oral History (Interview with Friedrich Hayek), American Libraries/Internet Archive, 1978. Retrieved on 4 April 2009 (Blog.Mises.org Archived 2009-06-27 at the Wayback Machine), source with quotes
  131. ^ "Best of Both Worlds (Interview with Milton Friedman)". Reason. June 1995.
  132. ^ Murray Rothbard, "The Future of Austrian Economics" on YouTube, 1990 talk at Mises University at Stanford, at MisesMedia Youtube channel.
  133. ^ Kirzner, Israel M. (2001). Ludwig von Mises: The Man and his Economics. Wilmington, DE: ISI Books. p. 31. ISBN 978-1-882926-68-8. OCLC 47734733.
  134. ^ a b "Subjectivism in the Austrian School of Economics." In Subjectivism and Interpretative Methodology in Theory and Practice, edited by Gary M. Shiu and Fu-Lai Tony Yu, Anthem Press, 2020.
  135. ^ Kirzner, Israel M. The Economic Point of View: An Essay in the History of Economic Thought. D. Van Nostrand Company, 1960.
  136. ^ Hayek, Friedrich A. The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism. Edited by W.W. Bartley III, University of Chicago Press, 1988.
  137. ^ Caldwell, Bruce. Beyond Positivism: Economic Methodology in the Twentieth Century. Routledge, 1982.
  138. ^ Weinstein, Eric. "Peter Thiel." The Portal, episode 1, Apple Podcasts, 2019. Link.
  139. ^ Mises, Ludwig von (1932). Gemeinwirtschaft: Untersuchungen über den Sozialismus (2 ed.). Jena: Gustav Fischer – via Internet Archive.

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Regarding personal names: Edler was a title before 1919, but now is regarded as part of the surname. It is translated as a noble (one). Before the August 1919 abolition of nobility as a legal class, titles preceded the full name when given (Graf Helmuth James von Moltke). Since 1919, these titles, along with any nobiliary prefix (von, zu, etc.), can be used, but are regarded as a dependent part of the surname, and thus come after any given names (Helmuth James Graf von Moltke). Titles and all dependent parts of surnames are ignored in alphabetical sorting. The feminine form is Edle.
  2. ^ On Mises's influence, see Rothbard, Murray, The Essential Ludwig von Mises, 2nd printing, the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1983; on Eastman's conversion "from Marx to Mises", see Diggins, John P., Up From Communism Harper & Row, 1975, pp. 201–233; on Mises's students and seminar attendees, see Mises, Margit von, My Years with Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House, 1976, 2nd enlarged edit., Center for Future Education, 1984.

Further reading

[edit]
[edit]